Hasil (
Bahasa Indonesia) 1:
[Salinan]Disalin!
1. IntroductionThe canonical model of portfolio choice (Markowitz, 1952), predicts first that householdswill hold a positive share in risky assets and second that managing risk will require ahigher diversification of an investment portfolio optimizing its risk-return characteristics.Previous empirical studies based on microeconomic data have verified that a greatfraction of investors hold very few risky stocks (Haliassos, 1995). A larger theoreticalmodel has been motivated by these results.Recently, there has been greater attention given to the lack of financial skills as a driverof poor financial behavior. The output measure of the financial decisions has most oftenbeen a lack of savings (Hilgert and Beverly, 2003; Lusardi, 2007), while recent researchstudies focus on stock market participation (Rooij et al., 2011), over indebtedness (Lusardiand Tufano, 2009), and mortgage delinquency (Gerardi et al., 2013).In recent years, the economic literature has uncovered two features of investorbehavior at odds with standard portfolio theory; the lack of portfolio diversificationand proximity investment, contrary to what standard theory would require, investorshold highly undiversified portfolios made up of a limited number of stocks (Barber andOdean, 2000) and they mostly select these stocks on the basis of geographical orprofessional proximity to them (Coval and Moskowitz, 2001).Also many recent papers have examined whether the financial illiteracy reflectsfundamental mispricing of the asset, over-optimistic expectations about future priceappreciation, or the buyer’s failure to correctly anticipate consumption risk, in thespecific context of financial plans for housing. The empirical results indicate thatfinancially illiterate households pay more for a given house than do more sophisticatedbuyers since the transaction price reflects the bargaining power of the buyer and theseller, and depends on the state of the credit market, the state of the housing marketand the information sets of the buyer and the seller (Turnbull and Sirmans, 1993;Harding et al., 2003).In the last papers, several authors have also associated financial literacy with theportfolio diversification (e.g. Kimball). Contrary to what is required by the standardtheory, investors own a greater undiversified portfolios which are composed of a smallnumber of different assets (Goetzmann and Kumar, 2005). In fact, most investors holdnearly all their wealth in local stocks (French et al., 1991; Goetzman et al., 2004),concentrate their portfolio in the equity market (Barber et al., 2003) and choose thesestocks generally on the basis of geographical or professional proximity (Coval andMoskowitz, 1999; Curcuru et al., 2005).Therefore, rational and informed investors are supposed to have diversifiedportfolios, irrespective of their levels of risk aversion. In the framework of traditionalfinance theory, important contributions have been made to explain why a rationalinvestor may own a less diversified portfolio than what might be considered optimal.Simultaneously, a group of alternative explanations draws interest to the fact thatthe thoughts about diversification vary systematically among groups of agents withdifferent characteristics (Shiller, 2002). Portfolio diversification may vary accordingto differences of the investors’ age (DaSilva and Giannikos, 2004), competence, wealth(Bertaut, 1998; Kumar, 2005), trading experience (Nicolasi et al., 2004), occupation(Christiansen et al., 2005).In this paper, we try to determine the extent to which differences in the investors’diversification behavior can be justified by differences in their financial literacy. We alsocontrol socioeconomic differences and behavioral differences among groups of investorsand consider three distinct aspects of financial literacy: specific financial knowledge, theinvestors’ educational level (used as a proxy for their ability to use gathered information)and the sources of information commonly used by investors as the basis for theirfinancial choices. Our results provide some potentially useful evidence on the investors’behavior in emerging financial markets. Most studies focus on well-developed financialmarkets and very little is known about the investor’s profile, motivations and behaviorless-developed markets. By using data from a survey of Tunisian individual investors,we contribute to bridging this gap.The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: we discuss the previousstudies and measures of financial literacy used in our work. The section afterthat presents the model, discusses the data, and describes the construction ofvariables and the estimation method used. The final section of the paper reports theempirical results.
Sedang diterjemahkan, harap tunggu..
