Hasil (
Bahasa Indonesia) 1:
[Salinan]Disalin!
What a wonderful honor to have our 1984 article(Hambrick & Mason, 1984) acknowledged inthis way by the editorial board of AMR. AMR haspublished a number of highly influential worksover the years, so it is surprising—and humbling—to learn that our contribution is seen assomehow worthy within such a lustrous league.In this update on upper echelons theory, I followthe suggestion of AMR’s editor, tracing theevolution and refinements of the upper echelonsapproach and articulating some of the challengesthat still need to be explored.1 I hasten toadd that the editor asked me “to educate thefield a bit concerning . . . [my] ongoing researchagenda in this area”; otherwise, this piecewould run the risk of seeming shabbily selfpromotional.Since I’m currently engaged in researchon narcissism in CEOs, I am keenly attunedto the obnoxiousness of first-personboosterism. In this case, though, I’m just followingdirections.RECAP OF THE INITIAL ARTICLEThe central idea in our original paper, and thecore of upper echelons theory, has two interconnectedparts: (1) executives act on the basis oftheir personalized interpretations of the strategicsituations they face, and (2) these personalizedconstruals are a function of the executives’experiences, values, and personalities. As such,the theory is built on the premise of boundedrationality (Cyert & March, 1963; March & Simon,1958)—the idea that informationally complex,uncertain situations are not objectively“knowable” but, rather, are merely interpretable(Mischel, 1977). If we want to understandwhy organizations do the things they do, or whythey perform the way they do, we must considerthe biases and dispositions of their most powerfulactors—their top executives.The paper also introduced two subordinateideas, each of which seems to have stimulatedmajor streams of research. The first of these wasthat a focus on the characteristics of the topmanagement team (TMT) will yield stronger explanationsof organizational outcomes than willthe customary focus on the individual top executive(e.g., CEO) alone. Leadership of a complexorganization is a shared activity, and the collectivecognitions, capabilities, and interactions ofthe entire TMT enter into strategic behaviors. Inthis vein, many subsequent studies have verifiedthat organizational outcomes depend, atleast in part, on TMT composition (e.g., Bantel &Jackson, 1989; Carpenter & Fredrickson, 2001)and processes (Eisenhardt & Bourgeois, 1988; Simons,Pelled, & Smith, 1999). The upper echelonsperspective does not require a focus on TMTs(and a number of significant contributions haveexamined CEOs or other individual leaders), butattention to executive groups, rather than to individuals,often yields better explanations of organizationaloutcomes.This article is dedicated to Phyllis Mason, who died inMarch 2006.1 I do not attempt to provide a comprehensive review ofupper echelons theory and research. For that, see Finkelsteinand Hambrick (1996), Carpenter, Geletkanycz, andSanders (2004), Hambrick (2005), and Finkelstein, Hambrick,and Cannella (in press). Academy of Management Review2007, Vol. 32, No. 2, 334–343.Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may notbe copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without thecopyright holder’s express written permission. Users may print, download, or emailarticles for individual use only.334The second subordinate idea is that the demographiccharacteristics of executives can beused as valid, albeit incomplete and imprecise,proxies of executives’ cognitive frames. Giventhe great difficulty obtaining conventional psychometricdata on top executives (especiallythose who head major firms), researchers canreliably use information on executives’ functionalbackgrounds, industry and firm tenures,educational credentials, and affiliations to developpredictions of strategic actions. Granted,the use of demographic indicators leaves us at aloss as to the real psychological and social processesthat are driving executive behavior,which is the well-known “black box problem”(Lawrence, 1997). Nonetheless, researchers havegenerated substantial evidence that demographicprofiles of executives (both individualexecutives and TMTs) are highly related to strategyand performance outcomes (Boeker, 1997;D’Aveni, 1990; Eisenhardt & Schoonhoven, 1990).And some researchers have ventured to peerinside the black box, examining the psychologicaland social processes that mediate betweenexecutives’ demography on the one hand andtheir behaviors on the other (e.g., Smith, Smith,Olian, Sims, O’Bannon, & Scully, 1994; Simons etal., 1999).LATER REFINEMENTS OF THE THEORYAlthough the original articulation of upperechelons theory, in the 1984 AMR article, engendereda sizable and enduring stream of empiricalinvestigations, there have also been severalenhancements of the theory itself. Among themost notable refinements have been the introductionof two important moderators—managerialdiscretion and executive job demands—which affect the theory’s predictive strength.Two Moderators of Upper Echelons PredictionsSydney Finkelstein and I introduced the conceptof managerial discretion (Hambrick &Finkelstein, 1987) as a way to reconcile two thenopposingviews about the effects of top executiveson organizational outcomes. One view,coming out of the prevailing tradition of strategicmanagement, was that top executivesgreatly influence what happens to their organizations.The competing view, coming out of populationecology (e.g., Hannan & Freeman, 1977)and new institutional theory (e.g., DiMaggio &Powell, 1983), was that executives have littleeffect because organizations are exceedingly inertial,swept along by external forces, and constrainedby a host of conventions and norms.Finkelstein and I argued that both of theseviews are conditionally valid, depending onhow much managerial discretion—or latitude ofaction—exists. Discretion exists when there isan absence of constraint and when there is agreat deal of means-ends ambiguity—that is,when there are multiple plausible alternatives.Discretion, we proposed, emanates from environmentalconditions (e.g., industry growth),from organizational factors (e.g., a weak board),and from the executive himself or herself (e.g.,tolerance for ambiguity).The implications of managerial discretion forupper echelons theory are straightforward—and profound: upper echelons theory offers goodpredictions of organizational outcomes in directproportion to how much managerial discretionexists. If a great deal of discretion is present,then managerial characteristics will become reflectedin strategy and performance. If, however,discretion is lacking, executive characteristicsdo not much matter. Several studies have shownthat managerial discretion is a pivotal moderatorof upper echelons predictions (e.g., Crossland& Hambrick, in press; Finkelstein & Hambrick,1990).More recently, Finkelstein, Mooney, and I(Hambrick, Finkelstein, & Mooney, 2005) introducedanother moderator of upper echelons predictions:executive job demands. Although theprevailing image is of CEOs carrying veryheavy loads and operating under great pressure,the reality is that executives’ (includingCEOs’) jobs differ widely in how difficult theyare. For example, some CEOs operate in munificentenvironments, with well-fortified strategicpositions, and have very capable subordinates,whereas others have none of these cushions. Weargue that executive job demands stem fromthree sets of factors: task challenges (e.g., difficultstrategic conditions), performance challenges(e.g., demanding owners or board), andexecutive aspirations (e.g., strong personal desireto deliver maximum performance).As with managerial discretion, we envisionexecutive job demands as a potentially importantmoderator of the basic predictive strength2007 Hambrick 335of upper echelons theory.2 Executives who areunder heavy job demands will be forced to takemental shortcuts and fall back on what theyhave tried or seen work in the past; thus, theirchoices will reflect their backgrounds and dispositions.Conversely, executives who face minimaljob demands can afford to be more comprehensivein their analyses and decision making;thus, their choices will more greatly match theobjective conditions they confront.Empirical work on executive job demands hasnot yet commenced, and we anticipate that measurementwill be difficult. Still, it may be possibleto identify conditions of objectively light demands(e.g., monopolies or cartels) and heavydemands, or to examine abrupt increases in jobdemands (e.g., deregulation), or even to use labdesigns to manipulate job loads. These methodscould be used to explore a host of phenomena,including this central proposition: the greaterthe executive job demands, the stronger the relationshipbetween executive characteristicsand strategic choices.Additional RefinementsBeyond identifying managerial discretion andexecutive job demands as basic moderators ofthe upper echelons logic, refinements of the theoryhave extended in other directions as well.Among these, two elaborations on the basic conceptof the TMT stand out: intra-TMT power distributionsand TMT behavioral integration.Finkelstein (1992) took the lead in demonstratingthat TMT characteristics yield stronger predictionsof strategic behavior when the differingamounts of power of TMT members are accountedfor. For instance, he found that thegreater the proportion of TMT members with financebackgrounds, the more acquisitions companieswould make. But when he added weightsfor how much power the finance-oriented executiveshad within their TMTs, the results becameeven stronger. Finkelstein’s methodologyfor measuring executive power was comprehensiveand well-validate
Sedang diterjemahkan, harap tunggu..